Much is
being written lately about globalization. Free traders love to see more cross
border activity. Non-Free traders wish international trade would be less
prevalent. Belgian Walloons tried to stop a free trade agreement
between Europe and Canada. I was once in Seoul when a monk set himself on fire
and died to protest the coming FTA between S. Korea and the USA. Free trade and
globalization have become a central focus in the current US presidential
campaign.
Much of the
debate has to do with politics and ideological warfare applied to trade. But it
helps to know that there are basic economic forces to explain both the rise and
the fall of globalization. These basic economic forces have been described by
using something called a gravity model. Gravity is the force that attracts a
body toward the center of the earth or toward any other physical body having
mass. As Charlie would say – gravity is the thing that keeps us from falling
off the earth. It is also the thing that causes bird poop to come down on
unsuspecting heads. The pull of gravity between two bodies is proportional to
the masses of the bodies and inversely proportional to the distance between them.
Two large bodies close by have a lot of gravitational pull. Two distant small
bodies would have little pull.
Economists have applied gravity models to economic issues. St. Paul
and Minneapolis are two cities in Minnesota. Bloomington Indiana and Palo Alto
California are also two cities. A gravity model predicts that there would be more
trade between the larger close cities St. Paul and Minneapolis than between the
smaller distant cities Bloomington and Palo Alto. To apply this basic theory to globalization we
need to better define the terms mass and distance as they relate to trade.
Mass refers
to economic size but it should be the relevant economic size. For example, if two
distant small cities were very specialized art centers – then you might expect
a lot of trade in art objects between those two cities. Or if two large close cities had a mountain in between them, then that object might impede
trade between the two. Dig a tunnel or build a road through the mountains and
the situation changes. Much more trade would be expected.
These ideas
are easily applied to globalization. While the physical distance between
countries and cities did not change in the 1990s, the distance measured in economic terms did. For one thing technology great reduced the
costs of communication and transportation in the last 25 years. For another,
the fall of the Soviet Union and the demise of many dictatorships in Latin
America allowed people in dozens of countries the legal right to trade. Technology and political change were tantamount to pulling nations much "closer" together or removing a mountain. As they came closer they discovered the benefits of trade.
Harvesting
low hanging fruit is easy. But once the easy to reach apples are gone, you need a ladder
to get the higher ones. The picking process gets more challenging and more
costly the farther up you go. The same happened with globalization. It was easy to get rid of
thousands of tariffs. Those tariffs hindered growth in most countries so
the politics of tariff removal were easier. When world economic growth picked up and countries dropped many trade restrictions, it seemed like most people in
most countries benefited. Today it is harder to see how technology or politics would change again so dramatically so as to make international trade even more seductive. It was hard to see the things that might change in the future that would make serious dents in the costs of distance.
And then it
got harder to agree on liberalization. The tariffs that were left (on the higher
branches) were the ones that offered protection to a country’s farmers or steel
makers. But tariff protection was not enough to
satisfy some free traders. If barriers to goods could be beneficial, then why
not remove obstacles to trade in services (like airlines, banking, healthcare,
and so on)? If restrictions on cross-border investing and mergers and acquisitions
seemed unfair, why not remove those barriers too? If laws did not protect ones ownership of
intellectual or other property then why not make it harder for foreigners to
easily pirate your patents and copyrights?
Once the low hanging fruit was gone, the remaining trade barriers were
much harder to remove. With no earth-shaking transportation/communications inventions expected it is harder to convince voters of the needs for freer trade. This is why the so-called Doha Round of the World Trade
Organization remains unsigned though negotiations started in November 2001. The
average person says something like – yes, we want the benefits of trade but we
do not want to be exactly like other countries. We don’t want a one world
government. We don't want our our national champions weakened.
Inasmuch the advancement of free trade and free trade agreements has become even more political
and ideological. As we move to closer economic integration, the benefits of the potential trade are fuzzier and the costs of trade in terms of reduced national independence and stability seem scarier.
Further global trade integration is not impossible. It is just tougher. It is made even more difficult in an epoch of slow world growth. In a slow growth world economic mass is not increasing and it is harder to believe that trade will raise all boats. But it is easy to see the risks to any nation that lowers its barriers. In a world where growth is strong, there is less to lose. Growth means people are doing better, worry less, and are more willing to try something that makes them even better. Without much stronger economic growth I find it very hard to envision a world in which globalization advances.
What would have happened to our massive rise in new technical equipment over the past 20 years without much of it being designed and made elsewhere? If no Honda or toyota would be still be driving clunkers with low gas mileage?
ReplyDeleteOn the other hand would we still have a robust middle class without that trade expansion?
Nice points Hoot. Going forward is what it is. Going backward sometimes seems humane but it hardly helps. If we hunker down and don't play ball with India, China, and other very innovative countries, we will lose in the end.
DeleteExcellent presentation.
ReplyDeleteDonkey Shane
DeleteDear LSD. Interesting comparison of gravity to trade—never thought the two would be associable, but then I never thought the Cubbies would win a world series. I guess never say never.
ReplyDeleteGravity—per my sparse comprehension of Newtonian physics, quantum mechanics, and black holes—I think treats all matter/objects equally—e.g. it will suck things toward something at a constant rate. Lately, the info presented on the benefits of trade/agreements show much inequality of those benefits accruing to the partners. It would be very nice if trade could equalize benefits between partners, but I doubt trade will ever attain the degree of purity of effect that gravity imposes on the objects it affects.
As you say, “ . . . . the closer we move toward economic integration, the benefits of the potential trade are fuzzier and the costs of trade in terms of reduced national independence and stability seem scarier.” Yeah, like being caught in the inescapable gravitational pull of a black hole.
It’s certain that gravity is certain. However, the certainty that trade/economic integration will benefit all partners equally or almost equally is not—Ricardo’s law appears to have limitations and (at the time) unforeseen consequences (but apparent now). It crazy to me that a county would continue to run trade deficits, losing jobs and lowering its standard of living, and borrowing gazillions to buy imported goods/services simply because economic integration is considered inevitable—or is it? If not, then unlike Newton’s laws, the “law of economic integration” should be held at bay or at least mitigated until beneficial parity is realized. Otherwise, Einstein’s law of insanity will prevail. If the $40B trade deficit and attendant debt is not attended to we will be like the moth circling the flame of a sucking, gravitational vortex of a nasty black hole from which inescapability is certain.
Economic growth whether via trade or organic surely is desirable, but smart and mutually beneficial growth is better.
Good stuff Tuna. You go well beyond my meager goals in this blog. First, the gravity model explains why there might be potential for more trade between two nations. Second, the actual change in amount of trade depends on a lot of things as you say. Third, one of those things is economic growth. The more the growth the more likely it is that potential turns into reality. Fourth, trade probably never confers equal benefits on the partners. A baby sitter gets $20. You get a night with peace of mind! But if a partner is benefited then it might be willing to enter an unequal arrangement anyway. Finally, I think many of the things you mentioned are exaggerated. The strong relations between trade and debt and employment and so on -- I think can be explained by a host of other factors. I think trade gets a bad name unfairly. Sixth, I am wondering where my JD is.
DeleteDear LSD, per your third point. The potential for econ growth via trade for the U.S. apparently is elastic to infinity (since it can't generate any organic growth of consequence) . . . as long as it can borrow to fund the purchases . . . which also appears infinite. I don’t think I exaggerated U.S. borrowing to fund its insatiable appetite for deficit trading—nor the predictable consequence of Einstein’s law of insanity. The relationship between deficit trading, borrowing to do so incurring debt, and the loss of jobs to lower-wage countries while not having a correlation co-efficient of 1.0 surely would approximate 1.0 should a multivariable regression be attempted. A good endeavor to past the time for a retired macro man seeking a bottle rather than a frontal lobotomy?
ReplyDeleteNo cigar. There is no link between trade deficits and foreign debt. When a country has trade deficits it gets a surplus in its financial and capital account. The surplus indicates money coming back to the country via bonds, stocks, bank accounts, etc. Some of it is debt but most of it is not. So in fact there is no relationship between trade deficits and debt. Most of the debt you speak of comes from the government because it spends more than it takes in in revenue. This debt would exist with or without a trade deficit. This debt might be bought by foreigners with or without a trade deficit.
DeleteAs for employment, you are again on thin ice. It is very popular to associate trade deficits with falling employment but it just ain't so. Especially since the trade deficit is a tiny portion of GDP. To explain major employment changes you are going to need domestic stuff. And there is plenty of that. I am out of the regression business.