Tuesday, May 10, 2011

US Competitiveness and Charlie the Tuna

Charlie the Tuna was a figure in a Starkist commercial many years ago (circa 1961). Charlie confused tuna’s with good taste (culturally adept) with those that taste good. Anyway, we affectionately nicknamed one of our childhood friends Charlie the Tuna. Charlie is a regular reader of this blog and generally lambasts me about my negative attitude toward US manufacturing. Charlie is a devoted cheerleader for US manufacturing and he should have been proud when the US announced productivity figures this week.  More will be said about US productivity below.

But first, let’s discuss US competitiveness. While the “C-word” can probably mean different things to different people, we often associate national competitiveness with an ability of a given country’s products and services or its firms to duke-it-out with firms from other countries. China’s export success is often taken as evidence of that country’s increased competitiveness.  Persistent and growing trade deficits of the US are considered to be evidence of the opposite.

Competitiveness in the above sense can be affected by many things. For example, the US often argues that China unfairly depreciates its currency or gives unfair subsidies to its firms as a means to improve competitiveness. Of course, fundamental factors are also important, factors that relate to the ability of a nation’s firms to produce high quality and innovative goods at the lowest possible prices.  That is where the recent announcement of the Bureau of Labor Services (BLS.gov) comes in.  On May 5, 2011 a news release announced data for productivity and costs for Q1 2011. While this was ignored by most outlets that cater to normal people, Bloomberg had a story titled something like “Productivity advanced by a measly 1.6% while business costs increased in the first quarter of 2011.” Even that headline failed to be as interesting as other stories nearby like “Babies who stop bottle feeding at one year are prone to be really fat” and “Physicists at the University of Alabama uncovered a bio-marker for athlete’s foot.”

If you actually read the government press release you understand why this critical information essentially gets blown in a black hole in some distant universe.  I read it and found myself quickly adrift with sea nymphs and cheerleaders.  After my nap I decided to go to the BLS website and see if I could discern a story from the actual data and sure enough it was all there. There is a story and it basically says a couple of things. First, Charlie the Tuna should be very proud since manufacturing is clearly leading us out of the wilderness. Second, the numbers suggest that the government has to STOP stimulating the economy. If there is any way to improve US competitiveness, it is by keeping inflation low and government debt in control. Since neither of these points is obvious on their own merits, let me try to convince you they are true.

The first bit of data in the release is something called UNIT LABOR COSTS. This is like naming your kid Ora. No kid wants to be called Ora. No economic variable wants to be called Unit Labor Costs. So let’s just rename it ULC. ULC is a measure of how much labor cost is changing in a typical unit of output.  If ULC change is zero, it means that labor involved with producing, e.g. bagels, are not causing change in the cost of producing one bagel.  If ULC for bagels is increasing by say 10% that tells us that labor costs are responsible for a 10% increase in costs of making a bagel. Companies become better competitors when their ULC is slowing – or better yet, decreasing. So ULC is an important aspect of a company or a country’s competitiveness.

After increasing at a rate of about 1.8% per year from 2003 to 2007 ULC of the non-farm business sector increased by only about 0.3% in 2008 and 2009 and then declined by about 0.2% afterward. The experience of manufacturing companies was very different. During the strong growth period from 2003 to 2007, ULC grew by only about 0.2% per year. During the recession ULC grew at an annual rate of almost 5% only to decline again in the recovery quarters to -3.6% per year. While the experiences were different the outcome for the last seven quarters is the same – manufacturing and other non-farm businesses have seen ULC decline.

One conclusion is that the US is experiencing improved business competitiveness in the recovery period – and this improvement has been especially strong in the manufacturing sectors. What explains this? The most straightforward answer comes from the definition or calculation of ULC. There are two key factors that determine changes in ULC: labor compensation per hour and labor productivity per hour. Recall that ULC has to do with labor costs embodied in the average unit of output. So clearly, a change in labor compensation per hour will impact ULC. If the Bagel Workers of America obtain a 10% per hour wage increase and if they work the same number of hours you can see how this will raise business costs and ULC.

But how much ULC increases depends on productivity change – or what we call output per labor hour. Let’s suppose workers get 10% more wages per hour but also are able to produce 10% more output per hour? Total costs would rise – but the costs per unit of output would not. So now you see that both output per hour and wages per hour must be brought together to understand ULC.  And we learn the following:

o   Wages per hour growing faster than output per hour --- ULC rises
o   Wages per hour growing slower than output per hour --- ULC falls
o   Wages per hour growing the same as output per hour --- ULC constant

In the expansion years from 2003 to 2007, manufacturing compensation per hour was rising at about 3.5% per year. But output per hour was growing by 3.7% per year so ULC hardly grew at all.
When the recession hit in 2008 manufacturing compensation actually increased to an average annual rate of about 4.8% per. Productivity declined at a rate of -0.4% per year and therefore ULC was rising at about 5.2% per year.  While rising wages contributed to ULC rising it was the decline in output per hour that really hurt competitiveness.

Coming out of the recession in 2010 (Technically the recovery begins in the third quarter of 2009) and early 2011 manufacturing productivity recovered dramatically averaging about 6% per year. Wages per hour have slowed to a rate of a little over 2%. Thus coming out of the recession ULC is falling at a rate of about -3.6%. Of course, this is exactly what you want to see if the US is going to grow through exports. Moreover, this enhanced competitiveness gives firms the ability to provide more goods at low prices within the US – improving both national output and inflation.

The following table summarizes the key numbers discussed above.

                                                Average Annual Percentage Change
                                                Manufacturing companies
                    Compensation       Output                     ULC
                          per hour               per hour

2003 to 2007       3.5                      3.7                        -0.2
2008 to 2009       4.8                     -0.4                         5.2
2010 to 2011       2.5                      6.1                        -3.6

So what does this mean for policy? First, the usual business cycle factors will mean that compensation will probably soon increase by more than 2.5% per year and productivity will not continue rising at 6% per year. Thus ULC will probably increase.  The role of policy, then, is to slow this normal cyclical process as much as possible in two ways: (1) provide an economic climate such that wage growth does not quickly rise and (2) ensure that output per hour does not quickly decrease.

Here is where the stimulus and national debt come in. Monetary and fiscal stimulus raises inflation expectations. The Treasury and the Fed keep reminding us that inflation is subdued. But it won’t be forever. Signs of inflation are around us everywhere. If we want competitiveness and manageable ULC, then we have to effectively and credibly convey a strong disdain for inflation. If workers do not believe that stimulus will be removed in a timely manner then they will quickly and decisively pursue faster wage growth.  I buttress this forecast by looking at the real value of hourly compensation. Since 2002 the buying power of the hourly compensation in manufacturing companies has grown by less than 1% per year. While manufacturing workers during those years got hourly wage increases – they were barely enough to meet inflation. They are more than ready to make up for lost time.

But wages and inflation are only part of the story. The rest concerns productivity or output per hour. To maintain competitiveness, US firms must continue to invest in new equipment, structures, training, etc. To do that they need abundant and well priced capital. With government finance sucking up more money than US households can supply from their meager savings, this reduces the pool of available resources and significantly raises interest rates and the cost of capital. Any further indications that the US will not be able to pay its obligations will lead to a hasty departure of foreign funds and even higher costs of borrowing and/or raising capital.

Quick progress to reduce deficits and national debt will go a long way to improving productivity, the cost of labor, ULC, and US competitiveness. You would think that our goofs in government would come to understand this and stop playing with ideological bombs and class warfare.  The below chart shows (found at (http://research.stlouisfed.org/fredgraph.png?g=pj ) how important manufacturing ULC is to the health of the US economy. Notice how significant upward trends in ULC led to recessions after 1990 and 2000. While ULC was well-behaved before the last recession we all know the important role of finance in that one. But also notice that the recent recession has left us with historically high ULC. Despite recent improvement it is clear that ULC has a long way to go before it reaches more normal levels. Until then our competitiveness AND our national economic growth are in jeopardy.

Note – if you cannot see the below graph properly, please try the above link.






12 comments:

  1. My skeptical nature makes me wonder if the ULC contains data concerning products made by U.S.-based companies but which are actually produced outside our borders. For example, last week I bought three pairs of shoes at a Bass Clothing Store. Bass is a fine, long-time U.S. shoe manufacturer, penny loafers and such. However, all three pairs were manufactured offshore. Obviously, the little fingers that stitched those six shoes together made about $.95/hour in some place like Xtapluana MX (Don't look. I made it up.) I'll go out on a skinny limb and say that the majority of products we consume today fit that mold. How does the ULC account for that assumption?

    ReplyDelete
  2. Dear Crash,

    You skeptical? I never would have thought it. :-)
    I used to wear Bass and Bostonian in high school. I had to mow quite a few lawns to pay but it was worth it. I believe that most shoe manufacturing moved overseas about 20 years ago. I don't think many shoes are made here anymore. As for ULC, those are US located manufacturers and should not count any imported product. Just like the GDP statistics net out anything produced abroad, so does ULC. Imports to the US of goods and services were about $2.6% trillion on an annualized basis in Q1 2011 -- about 17% of GDP. These figures include services which are a large part of GDP and a small part of the imports. So a rough guess would be that we import about 25-30% of all goods manufactured.

    ReplyDelete
  3. So, as the Tuna says, we basically no longer have a domestic manufacturing base....or did you say that? Let me see if I thoroughly understand. Even if Bass has its shoes made offshore then brought here to sell, they are counted as being manufactured here since Bass is a U.S. company. That smacks of governmental fraud-in-advertising. But then the Feds would NEVER intentionally mislead the public.

    I didn't wear Weejuns until I got to GT. Remember, I'm from Alabama. We didn't have shoes there, and we all have hook worms. Incidentally, the tooth brush was invented in Alabama. If it had been invented anywhere else it would be called a teeth brush.
    What's the problem with Ora for a name. We named our eldest daughter Ora Jel. Has a nice ring to it, doesn't it?

    ReplyDelete
  4. Crash,

    No no no. If Bass makes shoes overseas and then sells them here -- this is NOT counted in GDP nor in the ULC figures. The value added created in the sales is counted -- but none of the manufacturing. When you hear that GDP is $XXX trillion it is counting only value added in the US. It is NOT counting any overseas production. If your daughter married Petro Jelly then she would have been called Ora Jel Jelly.

    ReplyDelete
  5. Then the sample size for GDP (I was a GDI, myself) and ULC is relatively small these days.

    I'm just glad she didn't marry Naval Jelly.

    ReplyDelete
  6. I found a government database that shows how much manufacturing output has declined as a share of GDP. In 1947 mfg was 26% of all output. It rose in the next 10 years to 27% in 1957. In 1967 it was 25%, then 22% in 1977, 17% in 1987, 15% in 1998, and 12% in 2010. One thing to keep in mind -- the actual output of manufacturing has done nothing but rise -- it was $1.65 trillion in 2010. Furthermore, the long-term decline suggests that the cause was and is industrialization -- replacing labor with capital. While some of this is caused by globalization -- you can't escape the fact that most of what we have seen lately has more to do with domestic competition than China...

    ReplyDelete
  7. Other than a relatively few automobiles, what are we actually manufacturing here in the contiguous 48 states? Certainly not clothes and shoes to any great extent. The furniture makers have mostly gone offshore. Electronics such as TVs, radios, iPods, etc aren't even assembled here anymore. What domestic competition can there be? For all intents and purposes, we are almost totally a service-based economy. I suppose that does figure into GDP, but it doesn't give me comfort to know that when I call AT&T tech support, I have greater success if I speak Hindi.

    BTW, if you ever talk with the bean counters who put all of those government charts and data bases together, you probably wouldn't put so much stock in the data. Really good bean counters don't go to work for the guvmint.

    ReplyDelete
  8. Crash,

    You are not an easy mark. When faced with data you simply dismiss government bean counters as inferior. After a career in economics you somehow think I have never met or talked to a government bean counter. I guess that doesn't say much for me. So if I can't refer to any government data then I am not sure what I can do. While it is true that globalization has eliminated many jobs, industrialization has probably shewed up many more of them. Think about the very long haul when farmers learned how to replace field workers with tractors and other equipment. That is what we mean by industrialization. Think also of how much manufacturing output was created as we morphed away from agriculture. Clearly over the last 100 years much more output has been created than has been destroyed. Globalization is not a critical factor until at least 1990 and then it was a real trickle in so far as lost output was concerned. Whether you believe it or not, manufacturing output in the US has grown and since you are so distrustful of the data I will not bother you with actual sources of the output information. Yes, services output has grown more briskly but that does not mean that manufacturing output has not.

    ReplyDelete
  9. You forget. The Air Force sentenced me to 3 1/2 years in the Pentagon where I had first-hand experience with bean counters of every ilk. The worst were the ones from the Hill. I may never recover my trust of bean counters, and I have a son-in-law who are one.

    ReplyDelete
  10. I don't want to get into a pissing contest over data but it is one of those things can't live with and you can't live without. We all know that data is imperfect but the question is whether or not it gives us a reflection of or guide to what is going on out there. Worrying that GDP rose by 3.4% or 3.5% seems wasteful to me. But knowing it is growing at 3% and not 1% is important. The macroeconomic data is not perfect but at least in the US and Europe I think you can count on it being mostly indicative and not manipulated by the government or Dr. No. I am sure your family dinners are exciting with your son-in-law....

    ReplyDelete
  11. This is just a test to see if the comment function is working again. Apparently the site was down for a while and some comments were not reinstated. If you see this comment then it must be working again.

    ReplyDelete
  12. I'm sorry! I didn't mean to break it!

    ReplyDelete